X < back
X
Search
En/ Students/ Summer School

Students

【Fifth】Yong Wang: Remodeling Structural Change

2018-07-20

Content introduction:

Keynote Lecture Brief




Speaker:Yong Wang
Topic:Remodeling Structural Change





The lecture first introduced the background and significance of New Structural Economics, then went over two concrete papers as examples to see what New Structural Economics looks like. Prof. Wang together with campers seriously thought about the appropriate method to analyze dynamic structural change, even from purely mathematical point of view.


Background and Significance of New Structural Economics

In modern growth model, economists only think about aggregate production function:         


where Y is GDP, A is total productivity, K is physical capital, H refers to human capital, and L is labor. Unfortunately, this one-sector model induces people to focus on quantitative differences instead of structural differences between rich and poor countries, which easily results in misleading policy recommendations.


For example, in this one-sector model, a crucial factor that accounts for cross-country income difference is TFP. What prevent the poor country from adopting foreign advanced technology? Unfortunately, people come up with wrong ideas of this right question. One wrong idea is Old Structuralism, which suggests developing countries should adopt, even replicate, the same technology and industrial structures as in the developed country to have higher TFP. However, history has told us that sort of strategy does not work, as the optimal industry structure is endogenous. Another wrong view for this kind of question is called Neoliberalism. Neoliberalism highlights the role of market institutions, such as markets, property rights and even democracy, and it argues that, if poor country has the same institution as observed in developed countries, economic prosperity will come automatically. Unfortunately, those countries which adopted “shock therapy” basically collapsed. China, on the contrary, has adopted a gradual piece-meal reform approach and achieved the miraculous growth, although many people kept predicting China’s collapse for the past forty years. Neoliberalism fails to understand that the optimal institution itself is endogenous to development stages and erroneously sets the market institutions in developed countries as the only reference for all countries at different development stages, so economists brainwashed by this idea often provide prescriptions even before diagnosis when giving policy recommendations to less developed economies.


New Structural Economics is different from these two thoughts. High technology level and perfect institutions are certainly important, but they are both endogenous to development stages. Unfortunately, existing economic theories do not fully embrace the crucial importance of structures. However, structural change/transformation, a strand of growth theory literature, does try to address the Kuznets Facts, observed by Nobel prize winner Kuznets, namely,  as country’s per capita income increases, the agricultural employment share declines, the manufacturing employment share first increases and then declines, and the service share keeps going up.


What is the key difference between New Structural Economics and the existing structural transformation literature?  It is the driving force of structural change. New Structural Economics highlights the endowment-driven structural change, that is, the source reallocation among different sectors is driven by improvement of endowment structures. The simplest case of endowment structure is capital-labor ratio. While other structural change literature highlights other mechanism such as non-homothetic preference and unbalanced productivity growth across different sectors.


Briefly speaking, New Structural Economics uses Neoclassical approach to investigate the determinants, evolution and implications of economic structures in each different development stage along the growth path.


The dimensions of “structure” could be very broad. New Structural Economics  not only studies economic structures, but also political structures, government structures, etc. What is most frequently mentioned in New Structural Economics is endowment structures, which refer to the composition of different production factors and initial conditions such as geography and climate. NSE also studies financial structures, spatial structure and education structures, among others.


When we come to structures with different sectors, we have to think about heterogeneity. There are different heterogeneities across different sectors. Sectors could be different in capital intensity, skill intensity, productivity growth rates, gender intensity, income demand elasticities, tradability, and positions at the input-output table. We could study how different the compositions of those heterogeneous sectors are at different development stages and explore how these compositions change endogenously over time.

Remodeling Structural Change
Prof. Wang introduced two papers he wrote with his coauthors. The first paper, “Endowment Structures, Industrial Dynamics and Economic Growth”, published on Journal Monetary Economics in 2015, could serve as a candidate of the theoretical benchmark model for further explorations on various topics on New Structural Economics. This paper establishes capital accumulation as the new and independent mechanism that drives structural change. The model has an infinite time horizon and infinite sectors (the structural change is endless). This setting allows us to analyze the complete life-cycle dynamics of every industry at the disaggregated levels during the whole growth process. The closed-form solutions are obtained even though the model looks complicated. 


The paper first establishes four stylized facts about industrial dynamics using the NBER-CES data set of US manufacturing sector:

Fact 1: (cross-industry heterogeneity): There exists tremendous cross-industry heterogeneity in capital-labor intensities.

Fact 2: (hump-shaped industrial dynamics): An industry typically exhibits a hump-shaped life cycle: its value-added share (or employment share) first increases, reaches the peak, and then declines.

Fact 3: (timing fact): The more capital intensive an industry, the later it reaches its peak
Fact 4: (congruence fact): The further away an industry’s capital intensity deviates from the economy’s endowment structure (measured by the capital-labor ratio), the smaller is the industry


The paper takes Fact 1(cross-industry heterogeneity in capital intensities) as given and develops a dynamic model to simultaneously explain Facts 2, 3, and 4. The model first solves a static problem and attains the production function of final good which is endogenous determined by the endowment structure.


Then the paper sets up a dynamic model to fully characterize the industrial dynamics along the growth path of the aggregate economy, where the capital changes endogenously over time. By solving the dynamic model explicitly, this paper forcefully characterizes how such endowment-driven structural change could explain facts 2,3,4 above simultaneously. Consequently, this paper demonstrates in the first-best world how the optimal industries should be different at each different development stage and how they evolve endogenously. In addition, this mechanism is different from the trade specialization mechanism of the HO trade model because it shows how endowment structural change drives the industrial upgrading in a closed economy.


Middle Income Trap
The second paper, “Structural Change, Industrial Upgrading, and Middle-Income Trap”, is joint with Professor Justin Yifu Lin. Current growth theory could explain why developed countries can be persistently rich and why so many low-income countries fell into the poverty trap. However, it tells us very little about middle-income trap, which refers to the phenomenon that middle-income countries mostly fail to graduate from the middle-income status and become high-income countries. The existing theory typically only thinks about dichotomy: developing countries versus developed countries. But even among developing countries there are many different income levels. Middle-income countries face a dramatically different array of growth challenges from low-income countries. This paper proposes a plausible theory to explain the middle-income trap from the angle of structural change and industrial upgrading. The service sector in model is divided into three categories:

Production service such as financial service and transportation, which is intermediate inputs for final goods.

Consumption service such as hotel, restaurant, and entertainment, which is directly used for consumption.
Social service such as education, medical care, pension, which also serves for social purposes.


The paper argues that production service plays the key role in explaining the middle-income trap. The importance of production service is different at different stages. In low-income countries, people mainly produce low-quality manufacturing goods, which do not require very advanced production service as inputs. However, in a middle-income country, people want to have more consumption service and high-quality manufacturing consumption goods due to non-homothetic preference. Therefore,  high entry barrier to upstream production service may become a bottleneck constraint for structural change and industrial upgrading for middle-income countries, because production of consumption service and high-quality manufacturing both require production service more intensively than basic manufacturing. The paper also shows that the market equilibrium might be inefficient because of the pecuniary externality in the context of input-output linkage and structural change. It is shown that in Lassie fare market equilibrium, middle-income countries sometimes have premature structural change: moving from manufacturing into service sector too early even though there is still room for industry upgrading within manufacturing sectors. Sometimes market equilibrium without government intervention may also induce delayed industrial upgrading and structural change. Efficient industrial upgrading and structural change require coordination in the production service sector.

Conclusion
In this lecture, Prof. Wang argues that we should remodel structural change by formalizing different mechanisms that fully take into account sector heterogeneity and economic structures at different development levels. Only after understanding the key structural differences between countries at different development states and the driving forces behind these structural changes are we able to formulate relevant policy recommendations to improve the efficiency of resource allocation and enhance the welfare of the society. The JME model can be a useful working horse for such endeavor. 





Reference:




Written by: Weisheng Zhang

    Proofread by: Prof. Yong Wang

    Xiaomeng Ren